THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT:
Classical
theories
Contemporary theories Firm internationalization
FDI and Non-FDI explanations
Comparative advantage
Comparative
advantage is an economic theory about the potential gains from trade for
individuals, firms, or nations that arise from differences in their factor
endowments or technological progress. In an economic model, an agent has a
comparative advantage over another in producing a particular good if he can
produce that good at a lower relative opportunity cost or autarky price, i.e.
at a lower relative marginal cost prior to trade. The closely related law or
principle of comparative advantage holds that under free trade, an agent will
produce more of and consume less of a good for which he has a comparative
advantage.
David
Ricardo developed the classical theory of comparative advantage in 1817 to
explain why countries engage in international even when one country's workers
are more efficient at producing every single good than workers in other
countries. He demonstrated that if two countries capable of producing two
commodities engage in the free market, then each country will increase its
overall consumption by exporting the good for which it has a comparative
advantage while importing the other good, provided that there exist differences
in labor productivity between both countries.
Widely
regarded as one of the most powerful yet counter-intuitive insights in
economics, Ricardo's theory implies that comparative advantage rather than
absolute advantage is responsible for much of international trade
A famous
example, Ricardo considers a world economy consisting of two countries,
Portugaland England, which produce two goods of identical quality. In Portugal,
the a priori more efficient country, it is possible to produce wine and cloth
with l ess labor than it would take to produce the same quantities in England.
However, the relative c osts of producing those two goods differ between the
countries.
In order to produce an additional unit of cloth, England must commit 100 la bor hours, which could have instead produced 5/6 units of wine. Although Portugal can produce a unit of cloth with fewer hours of work (90 hours) than England, it must forego producing a greater amount of wine 9/8 (units) to do so. Accordingly , England is said to possess a comparative a dvantage in cloth even though Portugal possesses an absolute advantage in cloth. A similar argu ment would show that Portugal has both an absolute and comparative advantage in wine.
In the absence of trade, England requires 220 hours of work to both produce a nd consume one unit each of cloth and wine while Portugal requires 170 hours of work to prod uce and consume the same quantities. If each country specializes in the good for which it ha s a comparative advantage, then the global produ ction of both goods increases, for England can spend 220 labor hours to produce 2.2 units of cloth while Portugal can spend 170 hours to produ ce 2.125 units of wine. Moreover, if both countries specialize in the above manner and England trades a unit of its cloth for 5/6 to 9/8 units of Portuga l's wine, then both countries can consume at least a unit each of cloth and wine, with 0 to 0.2 units of cloth and 0 to 0.125 units of wine re maining in each respective country to be consum ed or exported. Consequently, both England and Portugal can consume more wine and cloth un der free trade than in autarky.
HECKSCHER–OHLIN MOD EL (H–O MODEL):
The
Heckscher–Ohlin m odel (H–O model) is a general equilibrium mat hematical model
of international trade, developed by Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin at the
Stockholm School of Economics. It builds on David R icardo's theory of
comparative advantage by p redicting patterns of commerce and production b ased
on the factor endowments of a trading region. The model essentially says that
countries will export products that use their abundant and c heap factor(s) of
production and import products t hat use the countries' scarce factors.
2×2×2 MODEL
The
original H–O model assumed that the only difference between countries was the
relative abundances of labor and capital. The original Heckscher–Ohlin model
contained two countries, and had two commodities that could be produced. Since
there are two (homogeneous) factors of production this model is sometimes
called the "2×2×2 model".
The model
has "variable factor proportions" between countries—highly developed
countries have a comparatively high capital-to-labor ratio compared to
developing countries. This makes the developed country capital-abundant
relative to the developing country and the developing nation labor-abundant in
relation to the developed country.
With this
single difference, Ohlin was able to discuss the new mechanism of comparative
advantage, using just two goods and two technologies to produce them. One
technology would be a capital-intensive industry, the other a labor-intensive
business
theoretical
Assumptions.
Both countries have identical production
technology:
This
assumption means that producing the same output of either commodity could be
done with the same level of capital and labor in either country. Actually, it
would be inefficient to use the same balance in either country (because of the
relative availability of either input factor) but, in principle this would be
possible. Another way of saying this is that the per-capita productivity is the
same in both countries in the same technology with identical amounts of
capital.
Countries
have natural advantages in the production of various commodities in relation to
one another, so this is an "unrealistic" simplification designed to
highlight the effect of variable factors. This meant that the original H-O
model produced an alternative explanation for free trade to Ricardo's, rather
than a complementary one; in reality, both effects may occur due to differences
in technology and factor abundances.
In
addition to natural advantages in the production of one sort of output over
another (wine vs. rice, say) the infrastructure, education, culture, and
"know-how" of countries differ so dramatically that the idea of
identical technologies is a theoretical notion. Ohlin said that the H-O model was
a long-run model, and that the conditions of industrial production are
"everywhere the same" in the long run.
Production output is assumed to exhibit constant
returns to scale
In a
simple model, both countries produce two commodities. Each commodity in turn is
made using two factors of production. The production of each commodity requires
input from both factors of production capital (K) and labor (L). The
technologies of each commodity are assumed to exhibit constant returns to scale
(CRS). CRS technologies imply that when inputs of both capital and labor are
multiplied by a factor of k, the output also multiplies by a factor of k. For
example, if both capital and labor inputs are doubled, output of the
commodities doubled. In other terms production function of both commodities is
"homogeneous of degree 1".
The
assumption of constant returns to scale CRS is useful because it exhibits
diminishing returns in a factor. Under constant returns to scale, doubling both
capital and labor leads to a doubling of the output. Since outputs are
increasing in both factors of production, doubling capital while holding labor
constant leads to less than doubling of an output. Diminishing returns to
capital and diminishing returns to labor are crucial to the Stolper–Samuelson
theorem.
The technologies used to produce the two
commodities differ
The CRS
production functions must differ to make trade worthwhile in this model. For
instance if the functions are Cobb–Douglas technologies the parameters applied
to the inputs must vary. An example would be:
Where A
is the output in arable production, F is the output in fish production, and K,
L are capital and labor in both cases.
In this
example, the marginal return to an extra unit of capital is higher in the
fishing industry, assuming units of fish (F) and arable output (A) have equal
value. The more capital-abundant country may gain by developing its fishing
fleet at the expense of its arable farms. Conversely, the workers available in
the relatively labor-abundant country can be employed relatively more
efficiently in arable farming.
Factor mobility within countries
Within
countries, capital and labor can be reinvested and reemployed in order to
produce different outputs. Similar to Ricardo's comparative advantage argument,
this is assumed to happen without cost. If the two production technologies are
the arable industry and the fishing industry it is assumed that farmers can
shift to work as fishermen with no cost and vice versa.
It is
further assumed that capital can shift easily into either technology, so that
the industrial mix can change without adjustment costs between the two types of
production. For instance, if the two industries are farming and fishing it is
assumed that farms can be sold to pay for the construction of fishing boats
with no transaction costs.
The
theory by Avsar has offered much criticism to this.
Factor immobility between countries
The basic
Heckscher–Ohlin model depends upon the relative availability of capital and
labor differing internationally, but if capital can be freely invested anywhere
competition (for investment) will make relative abundances identical throughout
the world. Essentially, free trade in capital would provide a single worldwide
investment pool.
Differences
in labour abundance would not produce a difference in relative factor abundance
(in relation to mobile capital) because the labour/capital ratio would be
identical everywhere. (A large country would receive twice as much investment
as a small one, for instance, maximizing capitalist's return on investment).
As
capital controls are reduced, the modern world has begun to look a lot less
like the world modelled by Heckscher and Ohlin. It has been argued that capital
mobility undermines the case for free trade itself, see: Capital mobility and
comparative advantage Free trade critique.
Capital
is mobile when:
There are
limited exchange controls
Foreign
direct investment (FDI) is permitted between countries, or foreigners are
permitted
to invest in the commercial operations of a country through a stock or
corporate bond market
Like
capital, labor movements are not permitted in the Heckscher–Ohlin world, since
this would drive an equalization of relative abundances of the two production
factors, just as in the case of capital immobility. This condition is more
defensible as a description of the modern world than the assumption that
capital is confined to a single country.
Commodity prices are the same everywhere
The 2x2x2
model originally placed no barriers to trade, had no tariffs, and no exchange
controls (capital was immobile, but repatriation of foreign sales was
costless). It was also free of transportation costs between the countries, or
any other savings that would favor procuring a local supply.
If the
two countries have separate currencies, this does not affect the model in any
way purchasing power parity applies. Since there are no transaction costs or
currency issues the law of one price applies to both commodities, and consumers
in either country pay exactly the same price for either good.
In
Ohlin's day this assumption was a fairly neutral simplification, but economic
changes and econometric research since the 1950s have shown that the local
prices of goods tend to be correlated with incomes when both are converted at
money prices (although this is less true with traded commodities). See: Penn
effect.
Related Topics
Privacy Policy, Terms and Conditions, DMCA Policy and Compliant
Copyright © 2018-2023 BrainKart.com; All Rights Reserved. Developed by Therithal info, Chennai.